• What the difference is between rival and excludable goods and services.
• What the free-rider problem is and what its consequences are.
• What the tragedy of the commons is and what its consequences are.
• How and when social norms, government regulation, and expansion of property rights can be used to solve problems with public
goods or common resources.
6 trang |
Chia sẻ: thanhlam12 | Lượt xem: 628 | Lượt tải: 0
Bạn đang xem nội dung tài liệu Chapter 19: Public Goods and Common Resources, để tải tài liệu về máy bạn click vào nút DOWNLOAD ở trên
11© 2014 by McGraw-Hill Education
Chapter 19
Public Goods and Common Resources
2© 2014 by McGraw-Hill Education
• What the difference is between rival and
excludable goods and services.
• What the free-rider problem is and what its
consequences are.
• What the tragedy of the commons is and what
its consequences are.
• How and when social norms, government
regulation, and expansion of property rights
can be used to solve problems with public
goods or common resources.
What will you learn in this chapter?
3© 2014 by McGraw-Hill Education
• There are two important characteristics that
determine how goods are used and whether
they are allocated efficiently by markets:
– When a good is excludable, it is possible for sellers
to prevent its use by those who have not paid for
it.
– When a good is rival in consumption (or just rival),
one person’s consumption prevents or decreases
others’ ability to consume it.
Characteristics of goods
24© 2014 by McGraw-Hill Education
Rival
Not rival
Excludable Not excludable
Four categories of goods and services based on
excludability and rivalry.
Characteristics of goods
Many goods lack one or both of these characteristics.
5© 2014 by McGraw-Hill Education
For each of the following, identify what kind of
good they are (private, public, artificially scarce,
or common resource):
1. Popular software.
2. AM/FM radio.
3. Street art.
4. A gaggle of geese.
5. A motorcycle.
Active Learning: Identify type of good
6© 2014 by McGraw-Hill Education
• Whether a good is excludable and rival in
consumption has important implications for how
it is allocated through a market system.
– Common resources are goods that are not excludable
but are rival.
– Artificially scarce goods are excludable, but not rival.
• Markets work well for allocating private goods
efficiently, but not always so well for allocating
public goods and common resources.
– Free-rider problem.
– Tragedy of the commons.
Allocation of goods
37© 2014 by McGraw-Hill Education
• The free-rider problem starts when someone
decides to not pay for a public good and enjoys a
“free ride” from those that have paid.
• The free-rider problem occurs when the non-
excludability of a public good leads to
undersupply due to a loss of revenue.
– Free-riders enjoy positive externalities from others’
choices to pay.
• Under positive externalities, the equilibrium
quantity is less than the level that maximizes total
surplus.
The free-rider problem
8© 2014 by McGraw-Hill Education
• Common resources are not a public good
(since they are rival), but they are
nonexcludable.
– Nonexcludability causes demand to be higher than
if people had to pay for what they consumed.
– Rivalry causes quantity to dwindle.
• This combination leads to the tragedy of the
commons; the depletion of a common
resource due to individually rational but
collectively inefficient overconsumption.
The tragedy of the commons
9© 2014 by McGraw-Hill Education
Active Learning: Identifying the problem
For each of the following, identify whether it
suffers from a free-rider problem, a tragedy of
the commons problem, or neither.
1. Earth’s atmosphere.
2. Children’s museum paid
by donations.
3. Common room microwave.
4. Litter at community parks.
410© 2014 by McGraw-Hill Education
• The problem with undersupply of public goods
and overdemand for common resources leads to
an inefficient quantity of production and
consumption.
• Solutions to these market failures fall under three
categories: social norms, government regulation
and provision, and private property rights.
• Strong social norms help rebalance the trade-off
by imposing costs on people.
– Social disapproval carries a higher cost in places where
people know each other and will interact with each
other in the future.
Dealing with public goods and common
resources
11© 2014 by McGraw-Hill Education
• Government bodies can impose consumption limits or
make up for inadequate supply when individuals
cannot.
• Bans and quotas are applied to common-resource
problems to reduce the inefficiency created by overuse.
• Making something illegal is one way of changing the
trade-offs that people face.
– If the punishment is not severe, or the likelihood of getting
caught is low, the cost may not be high enough to change
the trade-off.
– Bans and quotas fail in situations where it is costly for
authorities to monitor and punish rule-breakers.
– Tough moral and practical questions come into play.
Dealing with public goods and common
resources
12© 2014 by McGraw-Hill Education
• To combat undersupply of public goods, the
typical regulatory solution is government
provision.
• If the government is supplying a public good,
the efficient quantity is the one at which the
marginal social benefit equals the cost.
• Two difficulties arise when attempting to
provision:
– Calculating the marginal social benefit.
– How to finance the provision.
Bans, quotas, and government provision
513© 2014 by McGraw-Hill Education
• In some cases, the most convenient solution to
public good and common resource problems is to
privatize the goods.
• The patent system is an example of turning a
common resource (knowledge) into private
property.
– It assures corporations that others will not be able to
free-ride on their innovations.
• Assigning property rights over common resources
is often far from simple.
– Especially when many people are already using a
resource; it’s difficult to decide who owns what.
Property rights
14© 2014 by McGraw-Hill Education
• One common way that governments institute
private property rights is through the use of
tradable allowances or permits.
• These work the same way as externalities.
• They ensure that resources are allocated to
those with the highest willingness to pay, while
still limiting overall quantity to an efficient
level.
Property rights
15© 2014 by McGraw-Hill Education
• When a good is excludable, those who haven’t
paid for it can be prevented from using it.
• When a good is rival, one person’s consumption
prevents or decreases others’ ability to consume
it.
• Private goods are both excludable and rival.
• Public goods are neither excludable nor rival.
• Common resources are rival, but not excludable.
• Artificially scarce goods are excludable, but not
rival.
Summary
616© 2014 by McGraw-Hill Education
• The free-rider problem is caused by
nonexcludability leading to undersupply of a
public good.
• The tragedy of the commons is the depletion
of a common resource due to individually
rational but collectively inefficient
overconsumption.
Summary
17© 2014 by McGraw-Hill Education
• Strong social norms can help rebalance tradeoffs
in consuming public goods or common resources
– Imposes social costs on those who break the “rules” of
good behavior.
• Often, government bodies have the power to
solve the nonexcludability problem, while
individuals do not.
– Bans and limits address overuse, but are inefficient.
However, tradable allowances help to make them
efficient.
– Government provision addresses undersupply.
Summary
18© 2014 by McGraw-Hill Education
• Sometimes the best way to solve the tragedy
of the commons is to convert a common
resource into a private good.
– This can be difficult when it is not possible to
divide a resource or when it is not clear how to do
so in a fair way.
• Public-policy approaches can harness
individual incentives to manage use and
excludability.
Summary